Skip to main content

Publication records

Journal Article

Pricing when customers have limited attention

Management Science 64 (7): 2995–3014
Tamer Boyaci, Yalçın Akçay (2018)
Subject(s)
Product and operations management
Keyword(s)
Pricing, choice behavior, rational inattention, information acquisition, signaling game
We study the optimal pricing problem of a monopolistic firm facing customers with limited attention and capability to process information about the value (quality) of a single offered product. We model customer choice based on the theory of rational inattention in the economics literature, which enables us to capture not only the impact of true quality and price, but also the intricate effects of customer’s prior beliefs and cost of information acquisition and processing. We formulate the firm’s price optimization problem assuming that the firm can also use the price to signal the quality of the product to customers. To delineate the economic incentives of the firm, we first characterize the pricing and revenue implications of customer’s limited attention without signaling, and then use these results to explore Perfect Bayesian Equilbiria (PBE) of the strategic pricing signaling game. As an extension, we consider heterogeneous customers with different information costs as well as prior beliefs. We discuss the managerial implications of our key findings and prescribe insights regarding information provision and product positioning.
© 2017, INFORMS
Volume
64
Journal Pages
2995–3014
Journal Article

The role of leadership in salespeople's price negotiation behavior

Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 46 (4): 703–724
Sascha Alavi, Johannes Habel, Paolo Guenzi, Jan Wieseke (2018)
Subject(s)
Human resources management/organizational behavior; Marketing
Keyword(s)
Sales, leadership, price negotiations, salesperson–customer interaction, transformational leadership, social learning
JEL Code(s)
M310
Volume
46
Journal Pages
703–724
Journal Article

The escalation of competition into conflict in competitive networks of Formula One drivers

Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 115 (15): E3361–E3367
Henning Piezunka, Wonjae Lee, Richard Haynes, Matthew S. Bothner (2018)
Subject(s)
Human resources management/organizational behavior; Management sciences, decision sciences and quantitative methods
Keyword(s)
Competition, conflict, social networks, status, tournaments
JEL Code(s)
D74, J28
Volume
115
Journal Pages
E3361–E3367
Journal Article

Superstars in the making? The broad effects of interdisciplinary centers

Research Policy 47 (3): 543–557
Susan Biancani, Linus Dahlander, Daniel A. McFarland, Sanne Smith (2018)
Subject(s)
Technology, R&D management
Keyword(s)
Organizations, universities, knowledge, networks, interdisciplinarity, centers
Many universities have developed large-scale interdisciplinary research centers to address societal challenges and to attract the attention of private philanthropists and federal agencies. However, prior studies have mostly shown that interdisciplinary centers relate to a narrow band of outcomes such as publishing and grants. Therefore, we shift attention to include outcomes that have been the centers mandate to influence - namely outreach to the media and private industry, as well as broader research endeavors and securing external funding. Using data covering Stanford University between 1993 and 2014, we study if being weakly and strongly affiliated with interdisciplinary centers in one year relates to and increases (1) knowledge production (publications, grants, and inventions), (2) instruction (numbers of students taught, PhDs, and postdocs advised), (3) intellectual prominence (media mentions, awards won and centrality within the larger collaboration network), and (4) the acquisition of various sources of funding in the next year. Our results indicate that interdisciplinary centers select productive faculty and increase their activity on a broad range of outcomes further, and in ways greater than departments and traditional interdisciplinary memberships, such as courtesy and joint appointments.
With permission of Elsevier
Volume
47
Journal Pages
543–557
Journal Article

Willingness to rely on trust in global business collaborations: Context vs. demography

Journal of World Business 53 (3): 373–391
Francis Bidault, José de la Torre, Stelios H. Zanakis, Peter Smith Ring (2018)
Subject(s)
Strategy and general management
Keyword(s)
Inter-organizational trust; Propensity to trust; Willingness to rely on trust; Trustworthiness; Contextual factors in trust; Demographic factors in trust; Contractual safeguards; International joint ventures (IJVs) and collaborations
JEL Code(s)
M16
We examine how 712 executives from several countries, industries and backgrounds are willing to rely on trust (WTRT) when entering a collaborative venture where both partners are at risk. Presented with a specific partnership opportunity they were asked about the level of safeguards required to enter into an agreement. We test for the impact of contextual and demographic conditions and confirmed differences in WTRT between nationalities, but find that several contextual variables mediate this impact. Different nationalities treat three dimensions of trust (integrity, reliability, and benevolence) differently as they are shown to be time dependent. We conclude that context is as important as demography in determining an executive’s WTRT.
With permission of Elsevier
Volume
53
Journal Pages
373–391
Journal Article

Emergent leadership structures in informal groups: A dynamic, cognitively informed network model

Organization Science 29 (1): 118–133
Gianluca Carnabuci, Cécile Emery, David Brinberg (2018)
Subject(s)
Human resources management/organizational behavior; Strategy and general management
Keyword(s)
Organizational behavior, general management
This paper advances novel theory and evidence on the emergence of informal leadership networks in groups that feature no formally designated leaders or authority hierarchies. Integrating insights from relational schema and network theory, we develop and empirically test a 3-step process model. The model’s first hypothesis is that people use a “linear-ordering schema” to process information about leadership relations. Taking this hypothesis as a premise, the second hypothesis argues that whenever an individual experiences a particular leadership attribution to be inconsistent with the linear-ordering schema, s/he will tend to reduce the ensuing cognitive inconsistency by modifying that leadership attribution. Finally, the third hypothesis builds on this inconsistency-reduction mechanism to derive implications about a set of network-structural features (asymmetry, a-cyclicity, transitivity, popularity, and inverse-popularity) that are predicted to endogenously emerge as a group’s informal leadership network evolves. We find broad support for our proposed theoretical model using a multi-method, multi-study approach combining experimental and empirical data. Our study contributes to the organizational literature by illuminating a socio-cognitive dynamics underpinning the evolution of informal leadership structures in groups where formal authority plays a limited role.
© 2018, INFORMS
Volume
29
Journal Pages
118–133
Journal Article

Decomposition of solutions and the Shapley value

Games and Economic Behavior 108 (March 2018): 37–48
André Casajus, Frank Huettner (2018)
Subject(s)
Management sciences, decision sciences and quantitative methods
Keyword(s)
Decomposition, Shapley value, Potential, Consistency, Higher-order contributions, Balanced contributions
JEL Code(s)
C71, D60
We suggest foundations for the Shapley value and for the naïve solution, which assigns to any player the difference between the worth of the grand coalition and its worth after this player left the game. To this end, we introduce the decomposition of solutions for cooperative games with transferable utility. A decomposer of a solution is another solution that splits the former into a direct part and an indirect part. While the direct part (the decomposer) measures a player's contribution in a game as such, the indirect part indicates how she affects the other players' direct contributions by leaving the game. The Shapley value turns out to be unique decomposable decomposer of the naïve solution.
With permission of Elsevier
Volume
108
Journal Pages
37–48
Journal Article

Who needs a reason to indulge? Happiness following reason-based indulgent consumption

International Journal of Research in Marketing 35 (1): 170–184
Francine Espinoza Petersen, Heather J. Dretsch, Yuliya Komarova (2018)
Subject(s)
Marketing
Keyword(s)
Indulgence, consumption happiness, self-control, feeling right, emotions, luxury
While consumers and marketers perpetuate the lay theory that indulging with a reason is more pleasurable and makes everyone happier, this research identifies a condition under which indulging without a reason “feels right” and produces a more positive emotional reaction. The authors show that indulging with or without a reason and consumers’ trait self-control interact to influence happiness felt following an indulgent purchase. While high self-control consumers are happier when they have a reason to buy indulgent products (e.g., when they can justify the indulgence), low self-control consumers are happier when they do not have a reason to indulge, compared to when they have a reason. That is, indulging with a reason is less pleasurable for consumers with low self-control. This effect on happiness has an impact on downstream judgments about the product and yields important implications for consumer welfare as well as marketing managers. Across four studies we show the effect on consumption happiness, examine consequences of the effect, and report evidence for the underlying process.
With permission of Elsevier
Volume
35
Journal Pages
170–184
Journal Article

Financing capacity investment under demand uncertainty: An optimal contracting approach

Manufacturing and Service Operations Management 20 (1): 85–96
Special Issue on Interface of Finance, Operations, and Risk Management (Winter 2018)
Francis de Véricourt, Denis Gromb (2018)
Subject(s)
Management sciences, decision sciences and quantitative methods
Keyword(s)
Capacity, optimal contracts, financial constraints, newsvendor model
We study the capacity choice problem of a firm, whose access to capital is hampered by financial frictions, i.e., moral hazard. The firm optimizes both its capacity investment under demand uncertainty and its sourcing of funds from a competitive investor. Ours is the first study of this problem to adopt an optimal contracting approach: feasible sources of funds are derived endogenously from fundamentals and include standard financial claims (debt, equity, convertible debt, etc.). Thus, in contrast to most of the literature on financing capacity investments, our results are robust to a change of financial contract. We characterize the optimal capacity level under optimal financing. First, we find conditions under which a feasible financial contract exists that achieves first-best. When no such contract exists, we find that under optimal financing, the choice of capacity sometimes exceeds strictly the efficient level. Further, the firm invests more when its cash is low, and in some cases less when the project’s unit revenue is high. These results run counter to the newsvendor logic and standard finance arguments. We also show that our main results hold in the case of a strategic monopolist investor, and such an investor may invest more than a competitive one.
© 2017, INFORMS
Volume
20
Journal Pages
85–96
Journal Article

When serving customers includes correcting them: Understanding the ambivalent effects of enforcing service rules

International Journal of Research in Marketing 34 (4): 919–941
Johannes Habel, Sascha Alavi, Doreén Pick (2017)
Subject(s)
Marketing
Keyword(s)
Service delivery, customer–employee interaction, dysfunctional customer behavior, co-production, enforcement
JEL Code(s)
M310
Service employees frequently must enforce rules upon their customers to mitigate dysfunctional customer behavior and ensure proper service delivery (e.g., enforce “fasten seatbelt” signs on flights). However, the consequences of enforcing service rules (ESR) are not well understood. To elucidate the effect of ESR, the authors present seven studies involving > 6800 customers and consisting of cross-sectional and longitudinal data from customer surveys and company records as well as experiments. The results indicate that ESR exerts ambivalent effects: customers who experience ESR directed at other customers perceive service employees as more competent, which increases customer loyalty. However, if ESR is directed at customers themselves, they perceive a self-concept threat, leading them to devalue service employees' warmth and competence and to become less loyal. The effects of ESR hinge on a number of factors, including the harm that dysfunctional behavior potentially causes, the way ESR is communicated, and customers' experience with the service situation. Furthermore, the authors show that service employees can alleviate the negative effects of ESR by communicating service rules in advance and justifying ESR appropriately.
With permission of Elsevier
Volume
34
Journal Pages
919–941